By Subhashish Dey and Kunal Sen
Political incentives are known to play a role in the allocation of public resources from upper- to lower-tier governments. This column seeks to examine whether ruling parties in local governments favour their own constituencies in allocating MNREGA funds, if they target their core supporters or swing voters, and if this has any electoral returns.
An influential literature has highlighted the role of political incentives in the allocation of public resources from upper to lower-tier governments (Dixit and Londregan 1996, Dahlberg and Johansson 2002). So far, the empirical evidence on the role of political incentives has mostly focussed on intergovernmental transfers or grants, and there is limited evidence on whether partisan alignment is also evident for other public programmes, and how lower-tier governments allocate funds once they are received (Dasgupta et al. 2004).
Village councils (or Gram Panchayats, GPs), which are the lowest level of government in India, administer several social welfare programmes for the poor. Among the most important, both in terms of total funds allocated through GPs and households covered, is the Mahatma Gandhi National Rural Employment Guarantee Act (MNREGA)1, which is India’s largest anti-poverty programme2. GPs play a central role in registering households for the scheme, selecting the projects that should be funded by the scheme, as well as undertaking the projects with the help of local bureaucrats and MNREGA project staff once funds reach the village.
Do political incentives influence the allocation of funds by local politicians to their constituencies? Do they favour certain wards in their constituencies, and if so, do they target their core supporters or swing voters? And are there electoral rewards in targeting certain types of voters?
To address these questions, we examine whether ruling parties in local governments (GPs) in the state of West Bengal favoured their own constituencies in allocating funds for MNREGA and in providing MNREGA work to households residing in the constituency, and whether this had any electoral returns (Dey and Sen 2016). We used a rich primary dataset from 569 villages (or village council wards) over 49 GPs from three districts of West Bengal for 2010-20123. Local government elections took place in 2008 and 2013, allowing us to see whether there was a targeting of specific constituencies after the 2008 elections and whether this had any electoral pay-off in the 2013 elections.
During 2008-2013, there were two principal contesting parties in West Bengal with dissimilar political ideologies: a coalition of leftist parties – the Left Front (LF) – led by the Communist Party of India (Marxist) (CPI(M)), and the Trinamool Congress (TMC). The fact that there were two political parties in different parts of the state running the GPs allowed us to see whether there was any difference in the behaviour of these two parties in the manner in which they targeted certain constituencies and whether this led to differences in electoral rewards for the two political parties.
[su_pullquote align=”right”]Voters may prefer a particular party or candidate for reasons other than whether the MNREGA was implemented well in the constituency or not. [/su_pullquote]
To understand whether political incentives mattered in the allocation of MNREGA funds by local politicians, we faced two empirical challenges. Firstly, if we see a positive association between the allocation of public funds to a constituency or better MNREGA implementation and whether the constituency is under the control of the incumbent party, it could be due to the party’s innate preference to favour certain constituencies, rather than a deliberate strategy to win votes. Secondly, a similar challenge exists in establishing that the targeting of MNREGA funds to certain constituencies implied that voters in these constituencies rewarded the incumbent party with greater support in the next elections. Voters may prefer a particular party or candidate for reasons other than whether the MNREGA was implemented well in the constituency or not.
To address the first challenge, we looked at the constituencies where politicians of the ruling party marginally won elections at the village level versus the constituencies where they marginally lost. Since constituencies where the ruling party marginally won elections should be no different than the constituencies where they marginally lost, comparing the constituencies in this way allowed us to see whether MNREGA allocation of funds or its implementation in constituencies where the ruling party marginally won differed significantly from the cases where the ruling party marginally lost constituencies. If we did find that there was a significant difference, we could attribute this to the targeting of the winning constituency by the ruling party. To address the second challenge, we looked at the effect of increased MNREGA funds and implementation that could be reliably attributed to targeting of marginal constituencies by the ruling party on electoral returns of the incumbent party.
We find clear evidence that after the 2008 Panchayat elections, the ruling party at the GP level significantly spent more MNREGA funds in all the following years in their own party constituencies as compared to the constituencies of their opponents. Our estimates suggest that a village which is a ruling party’s winning village receives Rs. 38,750 more in terms of MNREGA expenditure compared to a non-ruling party’s village, and that households in the ruling party’s winning village receive 3.59 days more of MNREGA work compared with the households in the non-ruling party’s village.
Targeting swing voters vs. core supporters
In Figure 1, where we see a sharp jump in MNREGA allocation of funds to constituencies and days worked where the ruling party marginally won at just over 50% of the votes, versus constituencies where they marginally lost to the opponent party. This suggests that the ruling party in West Bengal targeted swing constituencies instead of the constituencies where they had core support (that is, constituencies where they had the majority of votes).
However, we find that the targeting of marginal constituencies differed between the two main political parties – while TMC-run GPs targeted marginal constituencies, CPIM-run GPs did not. As is clear from Figure 2, there was a significant difference in MNREGA fund allocation and implementation between the constituencies. TMC marginally won versus the ones they marginally lost. But we find no such difference in MNREGA allocation of funds or implementation between marginal constituencies won by the CPIM and the marginal constituencies that they lost (Figure 3).
What explains the difference in behaviour between the two political parties? We conjecture that the differences in behaviour between the two political parties can be attributed to the anticipation of regime change in the state as the TMC was making strong inroads in the GPs formerly held by the CPI(M), which provided little incentive for the CPI(M) to engage in targeting swing constituencies, as well as the class background of the potential beneficiaries of the MNREGA, who were agricultural labourers that have historically not been the core supporters of the left regime in West Bengal.
Figure 2. Effect of TMC being GP-level ruling party on village-level MNREGA outcomes
Figure 3. Effect of CPI(M) being GP-level ruling party on village-level MNREGA outcomes
Electoral returns
Policy implications
This shows that to understand why social welfare programme work well or not in the Indian context, more attention needs to be paid to the incentives of political parties to implement them well.
Subhashish Dey is at the New College of the Humanities in United Kingdom and Kunal Sen is at the University of Manchester.
Bibliography:
1. The Mahatma Gandhi National Rural Employment Guarantee Act (MNREGA), 2006 guarantees 100 days of employment in a financial year to every rural household whose adult members are willing to do unskilled manual work at the minimum wage.
2. In the state of West Bengal, about 80-90% of the total funds received by GPs from upper-tier governments is for the MNREGA.
3. The data has been collected by Subhasish Dey.
This article was originally published on Ideas For India.
Featured image : India Today
[su_note note_color=”#d2eaf6″]Fresh insights delivered to your phone each morning. Download our Android App today![/su_note]
Stay updated with all the insights.
Navigate news, 1 email day.
Subscribe to Qrius